Jump to content
DOSBODS
  • Welcome to DOSBODS

     

    DOSBODS is free of any advertising.

    Ads are annoying, and - increasingly - advertising companies limit free speech online. DOSBODS Forums are completely free to use. Please create a free account to be able to access all the features of the DOSBODS community. It only takes 20 seconds!

     

IGNORED

Credit deflation and the reflation cycle to come (part 2)


spunko

Recommended Posts

WTI is rocketing it's arse off as well, I think the FED have been called in to buy everything before all the plebs get on board xD

AND FOREX TOO, THE FUCKERS ARE SELLING SHITTY USD TOO!

YURO AND £ TO THE MOON :Jumping:

Link to comment
Share on other sites

  • Replies 35.1k
  • Created
  • Last Reply
1 hour ago, ThoughtCriminal said:

Anyone who thinks there's a free market is insane. Or is about to arse rape you. 

999398657_Screenshot2021-01-28at14_15_23.thumb.png.96a759f7e4707fe94afbfe0c763c5198.png

 

 

He kinda has a point, that i didn't really think off when i saw your post, also this is the fucked up thing like in march when people where trying to buy or sell but couldn't 

 

High prices or low prices are great if you can actually access it

Link to comment
Share on other sites

Bricks & Mortar
2 minutes ago, DoINeedOne said:

999398657_Screenshot2021-01-28at14_15_23.thumb.png.96a759f7e4707fe94afbfe0c763c5198.png

 

 

He kinda has a point, that i didn't really think off when i saw your post, also this is the fucked up thing like in march when people where trying to buy or sell but couldn't 

 

High prices or low prices are great if you can actually access it

They named their platform to suggest exactly the sort of activity they're shutting down and having none of.   Surely not good for company reputation.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

1 minute ago, Bricks & Mortar said:

They named their platform to suggest exactly the sort of activity they're shutting down and having none of.   Surely not good for company reputation.

Apparently people are allowed to sell just can't buy, but again if everyone now rushes to sell and Robinhood can't handle it 

Not everyone will get out with a happy ending

 

Link to comment
Share on other sites

1 hour ago, goldbug9999 said:

Yep totally predictable, if its free you are the product. Its well known that these so called "free" broking accounts sell your order details to high frequency trading shops to front run them.

Goldbug9999, I deeply suspect that is true, but do we actually know it happens for certain? i.e is it in the t&c's? I don't use those those free apps so genuine question. (though also suspect HL et al, do something similar, perhaps just by aggrogating their trading data or something, before selling it on?) 

As the world becomes more and more digitised, it is vital that we 'take back control' of our data, and/or maybe even get paid before releasing it. So many privacy/big state/subservience issues at stake here, but not much talked about, but that discussion is for a different thread. However, there are ways and means of achieving it, blockchain anyone...?

Link to comment
Share on other sites

2 minutes ago, JMD said:

Goldbug9999, I deeply suspect that is true, but do we actually know it happens for certain? i.e is it in the t&c's? I don't use those those free apps so genuine question. (though also suspect HL et al, do something similar, perhaps just by aggrogating their trading data or something, before selling it on?) 

As the world becomes more and more digitised, it is vital that we 'take back control' of our data, and/or maybe even get paid before releasing it. So many privacy/big state/subservience issues at stake here, but not much talked about, but that discussion is for a different thread. However, there are ways and means of achieving it, blockchain anyone...?

Think that horse has bolted. There's been a global crackdown on privacy coins, and a move toward KYC etc being mandatory for any crypto purchases.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

6 minutes ago, DoINeedOne said:

Apparently people are allowed to sell just can't buy, but again if everyone now rushes to sell and Robinhood can't handle it 

Not everyone will get out with a happy ending

 

That’s the point there isn’t a happy ending for most people, even if they manage to turn a few $100’s into a few $1000 so what. Nothing fundamental changes.  

This is a human wave attack, not everyone gets out alive
 

Link to comment
Share on other sites

2 hours ago, 5min OCD speculator said:

what a fucking bitch! I guess 'free markets' are fine as long as the 'banking elite' control the strings eh?

She'll be competing against Christine Lagrade next for 'complete control freak bitch of the century'!!! :Old:

What is it with women in power?

1 hour ago, Democorruptcy said:

American Airlines are currently up 80% in pre-market trading. They have 25% short interest, 152m shares.

Are we going to see firms have huge gains from people rushing to close shorts in case they are the next reddit target. Then if this reddit thing is closed down, a lot of firms that went up on fear, would then be worth shorting on fundamentals, IF.... you had the balls?

This is NOT advice xD

Youd be a fool to short against the fed...

SLV up 5% pre trade :Jumping:

Link to comment
Share on other sites

apologies to the LPP

hattip as ever @Democorruptcy

Highlights are mine to enable skim reading.TThe comments as ever are well worth a read,some knowledgeable folk on there and Dr Tim interacts heavily.

He starts early on with the point that CB's have bought nearly all new Gvot debt issuance and ends with the conclusion that soft default is the option of choice for the political class.

https://surplusenergyeconomics.wordpress.com/2021/01/22/188-can-we-track-the-fate-of-fiat/

#188. Can we track the fate of fiat?

Posted on January 22, 2021

OF WEDGE AND EXCESS

If the world economy is – as both logic and observation indicate – heading into involuntary ‘de-growth’, there is a choice to be made. Do we enter the era of economic contraction with a functioning monetary system available to help us manage it, and to mitigate its worst effects? Or do we sacrifice monetary viability in a futile effort at denial?

The former might be a great deal more rational, but probability increasingly favours the latter.

The coronavirus pandemic has not so much created as accelerated tendencies towards the use of financial expansion as a cure-all for both real and imagined economic ills. This puts two facets of monetary observation into conflict. On the one hand, we know that fiscal and monetary stimulus can help us to moderate economic downturns. On the other, though, we also know that too much monetary intervention carries the risk of undermining the all-important credibility of fiat money.

If ‘too much debt’ is one risk, ‘too much monetization of debt’ is another, and both seem to have gone into overdrive since the start of the coronavirus crisis. SEEDS data and estimates indicate that, during 2020, a group of sixteen advanced economies (AE-16) are likely to have run fiscal deficits of about $8.8 trillion, or 20% of their combined GDPs, a figure pretty much matching the $8.9tn that the four main Western central banks deployed in net asset expansion (QE) during the year.

Even if vaccination does indeed quickly bring the pandemic under control, continuing fiscal intervention – and the need to alleviate burdens placed on lenders and landlords by debt and rent payment ‘holidays’ – imply further big increases in public debt, and central bank monetization, during the current year.

Does this put the viability of fiat money itself at risk?

It’s certainly starting to look that way.

Not measured, not managed

Part of the problem is that orthodox economic interpretation cannot quantify what “too much” monetary intervention actually means. In the absence of such calibration, the authorities are at the mercy of short-term thinking and political pressures. Accordingly, those who express dark forebodings about the fate of fiat in a context of unprecedented financial intervention may very well be right.  

The original intention here had been to concentrate wholly on monetary issues. But the better plan is to locate the role of money within broader economic processes, and then to ask whether there can be better calibration of the concept of monetary “excess”.

The conclusion reached here is that we can use energy-based measurement of prosperity as an independent benchmark against which to measure the economic claims embodied in the financial system. This measurement indicates that we have already travelled too far down the road of creating excess claims to turn back without making enormous, hugely unpopular adjustments to the system.

As the old saying goes, “if it isn’t measured, it isn’t managed”. This describes our current monetary predicament very well indeed – if credit creation and monetary policy seem out of control, the lack of meaningful measurement is a major factor in what has become an unmanaged problem.

The inability of monetary measurement to calibrate “excess” in a meaningful way is a consequence of the use of equations whose components are not discrete (that is, they are not independent of each other).

The often-used ratio which compares debt with GDP is a case in point. If, for instance, additional credit is put into the economy, the effect is to increase the economic activity that is counted as GDP, meaning that both the numerator (debt) and the denominator (GDP) are inter-connected. Indeed, and in situations where the debt/GDP ratio already exceeds 100% – where, that is, debt already exceeds GDP – it is perfectly possible for a rise in the quantity of debt to cause a fall in the ratio between debt and GDP. This results in a systemic underestimation of the proportionate extent of debt, a process of understatement which becomes more pronounced as indebtedness increases.

In this knowledge vacuum – in which the term “excessive” cannot be defined – decision-makers find it very hard to resist pressures for ever more fiscal and monetary intervention. Those urging support, whether for their own sector or for the economy as a whole, can call in aid Keynes’ observations about stimulus, omitting to add that the Keynesian calculus addresses the smoothing of cycles, not a perennial stimulation of economic activity on a continuing basis, and envisages periods of financial tightening which offset periods of stimulus.

As remarked earlier, it’s likely that fiscal stimulus injected into sixteen Western economies totaled 20% of their combined GDPs last year, and may be of the order of 10% in 2021, with the former number essentially monetized by central bank money creation. This, on the face of it, looks like “excess”.  

So at what point, then, does financial intervention become “excessive”? Conventional ratios such as debt/GDP cannot tell us this, and neither, in a market distorted by huge intervention, can interest rates answer this question either. Another non-discrete measure – that which compares asset prices with liabilities – cannot help us to know where the “point of excess” lies. For various reasons – which include the conventional exclusion of asset prices from the calculation of inflation – we can’t even rely on inflation numbers for warning that the point of excess looms.

A claim on energy – the real meaning of money

To understand these issues, we need first to place money in its economic context. Conventional explanation ascribes three roles to money. One of these is as store of value, a function which fiat currencies cannot, historically, be said to have fulfilled. A second is that money can be used as a unit of measurement, but this, as we’ve seen, is an extremely flawed concept, primarily because there exist no recognized non-monetary benchmarks against which monetary numbers can be measured. This leaves us with the third – actually, the all-important – function of money, which is as a “means of exchange”.

Of “exchange”, though, for what? Clearly, the only meaningful process of exchange is one which involves the use of money to buy goods and services. This in turn defines money as a ‘token’. As such, money has no intrinsic worth, meaning that it commands value only in terms of the things for which it can be exchanged. This is why, in Surplus Energy Economics, money is defined as a ‘claim’ on goods and services.  

Money can usefully be likened to the ticket or ‘check’ given to a person handing in a hat or coat when attending an event. Printing more of these checks doesn’t increase the number of hats or coats available when the exchange process is reversed at the end of the function. Likewise, the ‘check’ cannot, of itself, keep its owner warm or dry – for this, it needs to be exchanged for an actual (physical) coat or hat.

With due apologies to those who already know this, the role of money as claim is one of the three core principles of the surplus energy economy. The first of these is that all of the goods and services which constitute economic output are products of the use of energy, such that nothing of any economic utility whatsoever can be supplied without it. This defines money as a ‘claim on energy’, with the corollary being that debt, as a ‘claim on future money’, really functions as a ‘claim on future energy’.

The second core observation is that, whenever energy is accessed for our use, some of that energy is always consumed in the access process. We can’t put oil to use without drilling a well or building a refinery, access gas without investing in wells and processing systems, make use of coal without excavating a mine, or harness solar or wind power without constructing solar panels, wind turbines and distribution systems. All of these processes are themselves functions of the use of energy. The “used in access” component is known here as ECoE (the Energy Cost of Energy).

This enables us to refine our definitions, such that money is ‘a claim on surplus (ex-ECoE) energy’, and debt ‘a claim on future surplus energy’. A logical question to ask ourselves is: what has happened to money, debt and broader obligations, in relation to surplus energy, in recent times?

Comparing 2019 with 1999, and using financial data adjusted for inflation, money GDP expanded by 95%, and debt by 177%, over a period in which global surplus energy increased by less than 50%. Throughout this period, these ratios became progressively worse.

What this means for underlying economic output, and its relationship with debt, is illustrated in the following charts. Since the mid-1990s, aggregate global debt (shown in red in the left-hand chart) has expanded far more rapidly than reported GDP. The central chart shows how, expressed at constant 2019 values, annual borrowing (in red) has been far larger than increments to GDP (blue).

The right-hand chart shows how the development of a ‘wedge’ between debt and GDP has inserted a corresponding wedge between reported GDP and underlying or ‘clean’ output (C-GDP).

This interpretation is wholly ignored by orthodox approaches, which fail to recognize the connection between the non-discrete (that is, the connected) entities of debt and reported GDP. Properly understood, though, the ‘wedge’ concept can provide important insights into the way in which the interaction between debt and GDP distorts both the real level of economic output and the extent of leverage built in to the system.  

image.png.77282f4728e867075fc12f9ebdef83ae.png

Prosperity as process

The identification of ECoE divides the supply of energy into two components. One of these is the cost element (ECoE), and what remains is surplus energy. Since this surplus energy powers all economic activity other than the supply of energy itself, surplus energy is coterminous with the material prosperity delivered by the economy. If monetary measurement of the economy departs in any meaningful way from this definition of prosperity, we can be said to be practicing financial self-delusion.  

Though ignored by orthodox economics, the ECoE process is reasonably well understood. In the early stages, ECoEs are driven downwards by geographic reach, economies of scale and advances in technology, with the proviso that the scope of technology is circumscribed by the physical characteristics of the energy resource. In the case of fossil fuels – which continue to supply more than four-fifths of global primary energy consumption – the potential of reach and scale has been exhausted, introducing depletion as the primary (and upwards) driver of ECoEs. The meaning of depletion is that, quite naturally, we have used lowest-cost sources of oil, gas and coal first, leaving costlier alternatives for a “later” which has now arrived. Technology can mitigate the ensuing rise in ECoEs, but cannot overturn the laws of physics such as to push ECoEs back downwards.

This has always meant that the end of fossil-fuel-powered economic growth wasn’t going to be a matter of “running out of” oil, gas or coal, but of encountering rising costs (ECoEs) which erode the economic value of each unit of energy accessed. Cost and volume parameters are interconnected, of course, so that rising costs must inevitably, in due course, result in decreasing volumes.

The great hope, reinforced by urgent environmental imperatives, is that we can replace rising-ECoE fossil fuels with falling-ECoE renewable sources of energy (REs). Imperative though the development of RE capacity is, some of the more glib assurances of seamless transition have always been something of a triumph of hope over analysis.

There are two main snags with the ‘seamless transition’ thesis. The first is that, though falling, the ECoEs of REs might never fall far enough to replace low-ECoE fossil fuels as drivers of economic expansion. The second is that, because RE expansion relies on inputs whose supply depends in turn on the use of fossil fuels, we may not be able to de-link the ECoEs of REs from the (rising) ECoEs of fossil fuels.

REs are already close to offering ECoEs that are competitive with, or below, those of fossil fuels today. What we require of REs, though, are ECoEs that replicate the ultra-low levels of fossil fuels, not now, but in their heyday.  For reference, SEEDS analysis indicates that prosperity in the advanced economies turned down at ECoEs of between 3.5% and 5%, with the same happening to less-complex, less ECoE-sensitive emerging market (EM) economies in an ECoE range between 8% and 10%.

What we require of REs, then, are ECoEs that are certainly less than 5% and, ideally, ECoEs which replicate those of fossil fuels – between 1% and 2% – back when oil, gas and coal were capable of driving real and sizable increases in material prosperity. 

The reality, though, is that it seems unlikely that the ECoEs of REs are ever going to fall much below about 10%. On that basis, the global economy – with an overall trend ECoE of 9.3% – has already entered a phase of deteriorating prosperity, a trend from which not even EM countries such as China and India can be expected to be exempt.

We can call this process “de-growth”, but with the proviso that this is not the voluntary contraction advocated by those who contend that the world would be a better place if we ditched our obsession with material “growth”. Rather, what we’re experiencing now is involuntary “de-growth”, imposed upon us by a deterioration in the energy equation which determines trends in prosperity.

Where reported GDP – inflated both by credit effects and by a failure to allow for ECoE – exceeds prosperity, the situation is one in which we are creating “excess claims”. Simply stated, this means that financial behaviour is creating (and distributing) monetary claims that the surplus energy of today and tomorrow will be incapable of meeting. If that’s the case, the destruction of the “value” contained in these “excess claims” becomes inescapable. To revert to an earlier metaphor, a lot of people are going to present ‘checks’ for which no economic hat or coat exists for the purpose of exchange.  

The following charts set out the “excess claims” interpretation of the relationship between prosperity (measured on an energy basis) and financial ‘promises’.

The left-hand chart illustrates the process by which reported GDP has departed from underlying prosperity. Whilst monetary expansion has – as we have seen – driven a wedge between reported (GDP) and underlying (C-GDP) output, the inclusion of rising ECoEs tracks a further divergence between C-GDP and prosperity.

The result is that a steadily widening divergence between GDP and prosperity has created successive annual increments of excess claims within the financial representation of the economy.

It must be emphasized that the central chart reflects ongoing development work on the SEEDS model. This project has reached a point at which we can produce a realistic illustration of the cumulative build-up of ‘excess claims’ over time. In the chart, this is set against global debt to show how the accumulation of excess claims has progressed far beyond the relatively straightforward expansion of debt, and now embraces many other and substantial forms of liability.

The left-hand and central charts are calibrated in international dollars PPP – this is the preferred convention in SEEDS, and converts other currencies into dollars on the basis of purchasing power parity. To facilitate comparison with debt and other statistics, the right-hand chart shows the global equivalents of debt and excess claims on the basis of market dollars.     

 

image.png.c9cb9fcccafe8e2e29393a4a8828b80a.png

The broad picture

This SEEDS analysis, as expressed in market-converted dollars, suggests that cumulative excess claims already exceeded $360tn by the end of 2019, a number far larger than formal debt at that time. With prosperity hit by the pandemic crisis, whilst financial claims are being created at a seemingly unprecedented rate, we can only assume that we are experiencing a big expansion in the ongoing (and the cumulative) gaps between real economic output and financial claims. 

We can further describe how this process is likely to unwind. Fundamentally, a big ‘excess claims’ gap means that borrowers will have no option but to default, and that asset prices will fall in line with the deterioration in future value that these prices are supposed to represent.

The question then becomes one of how this default takes place. One way is formal default, where borrowers are unable to meet their commitments. The alternative is informal or soft default, where obligations are met, but in money devalued by inflation. History reveals an almost invariable preference – wherever the choice exists – for the for informal (‘soft’) over formal (‘hard’) default.

Thus seen, the situation is clear, albeit disturbing. Over time, we have created monetary ‘claims’ which have diverged ever further from the prosperity generated by the energy-determined ‘real’ economy of goods and services. Evidences of this excess are to be seen across the board, not just in debt but in broader categories of commitment (which include huge unfunded and un-fundable gaps in pension commitments).  Asset prices have been inflated, in part by the cheap money reflected in excess claims, and in part by the persistence of unrealistic expectations for the future.

Our responses to this emerging situation have had all the predictability of a badly-scripted film. Faced with “secular stagnation” (a precursor to de-growth, and ultimately traceable to rising ECoEs), we responded with credit adventurism, based on the illogical premise that credit creation could somehow invigorate a ‘real’ economy which converts energy, resources and labour into economic utility. Whilst fiscal and monetary policy can smooth temporary peaks and troughs, it cannot change the underlying trend in value creation determined by thermodynamics.

This in turn pushed us, during the ensuing 2008-09 crisis, into monetary adventurism, a short-term response to credit excesses which, in reality, cannot be countered within any set of policies which aim, at the same time, to preserve the value of money.

It’s wholly unsurprising, then, that the coronavirus crisis has pushed us a long way further down the road to the discrediting of fiat money. A combination of short-term thinking, well-intentioned intervention, self-interest and fundamental misunderstanding has led us to believe that credit and fiscal stimulus can supply a cost-free ‘fix’ for underlying economic issues which, properly understood, are not responsive to monetary manipulation.

What the authorities have been doing during the pandemic amounts to a rapid acceleration of established policies which assume that, by injecting cheap credit and cheaper money into the system, we can go beyond the reasonable moderation of cycles into the unreasonable creation of perpetual growth.

This misunderstanding of economic fundamentals might be likened to the way in which trainee pilots are sometimes warned that “Isaac [Newton] is always waiting”. What sages of aviation – who tend also to remark that “there are old pilots, and bold pilots, but no old bold pilots” – mean by this is that gravity always lies in wait to punish aviators who allow hubris and ignorance to outweigh prudence and a proper respect for the laws of aerodynamics. 

The corollary here is that excessive self-assurance, and a failure to understand the thermodynamic basis of economic activity, have led us to play ducks-and-drakes with the viability of fiat money.

Conceptually, the existence of fiat has always made it possible for us to create monetary claims which exceed the capabilities of the real economy. The events and fallacies of recent years seem, beyond question, to have led is into precisely this fundamental mistake. We are – to paraphrase a former pilot – trying to fly under economic conditions in which “even the birds are walking”.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

geordie_lurch
2 minutes ago, Democorruptcy said:

HL are 'unable to retrieve a quote' on such as NOK and BB. It's fill or kill orders only, presumably because prices are all over the place.

$GME and $AMC have been halted apparently so not sure about NOK and BB :ph34r:

Link to comment
Share on other sites

1 minute ago, Green Devil said:

AG is halted, UP too high :CryBaby:

So if people are buying, they halt the stock? What a crock of shite. Too many crooks under water. The Silver shorts must be shitting their pants!

Link to comment
Share on other sites

5 minutes ago, Democorruptcy said:

HL are 'unable to retrieve a quote' on such as NOK and BB. It's fill or kill orders only, presumably because prices are all over the place.

My silver miner gambles as per the shares forum have paused at 'submitted for dealing'.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

1 minute ago, Noallegiance said:

My silver miner gambles as per the shares forum have paused at 'submitted for dealing'.

This is bloody hilarious and shows up the entire system for what a scam it truly is!

Link to comment
Share on other sites

42 minutes ago, geordie_lurch said:

Back down to $370 now premarket but TPTB have stopped people buying GME and others via Robinhood and other platforms which shows how rigged and potentially scared they are :PissedOff:

Yep, rigged financial markets, and rigged media outlets (social and broadcast)... interesting/depressing times.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

Archived

This topic is now archived and is closed to further replies.

  • Recently Browsing   0 members

    • No registered users viewing this page.

  • Latest threads

×
×
  • Create New...